Devan Pillay

New South African Review 4


Скачать книгу

2005).

      The weakening of trade unions in post-apartheid South Africa has to a large extent been masked by two phenomena: the participation of unions in the ruling Tripartite Alliance, and the massive unionisation of workers in the public sector which has prevented a collapse in the number of unionised workers (standing close to 3.1 million out of a total workforce of 13.5 million – see Macun, in this volume) while accelerating sociological and political evolution in Cosatu. This may explain why unions have failed to respond to capital’s systematic dodging of the new labour relations regime which they promoted. Rather than ‘co-determine’ anything with their workers, most employers have turned (often starting in the 1980s) to externalisation and casualisation.

      CONCLUSION

      This chapter has highlighted two trends in the post-apartheid labour market: its failure to address major socioeconomic challenges and the inefficiency of collective bargaining for protecting workers, combined with the weakness of direct state intervention in the labour market. The progressive restructuring of labour relations, starting with the creation of decent work opportunities for the majority of South Africans, has turned out to be a pipedream. Instead, the labour market has, like the economy and the state, been restructured in a neoliberal way which has entrenched the structural inequality between capital and labour (Segatti and Pons-Vignon 2013). Under apartheid, state power had been mobilised to advance the interests of capital. ‘Liberalisation’ – actively supported by the state before and after 1994 – has generated an even more unequal relationship by allowing capital to leave the country and leverage high unemployment to undermine the workplace strength of labour. The protection promised by post-apartheid labour law hinged on the existence of strong trade unions, which would have been able to advance the interests of workers through bargaining councils, but even if workers have benefited from the new legislation in some sectors, the increase in atypical employment has eroded trade union power and their ability to take advantage of it.

      Our contention, therefore, is that labour market restructuring in a context of economic liberalisation has benefited capital. The failure of a strong and militant trade union movement (with a few exceptions) to counter these moves is an uneasy reality for many. Macun (in this volume) suggests that unions’ organisational power and democratic control have been undermined in the post-apartheid era. This lies at the heart of the broader failure of trade unions to advance the interests of labour as a class – an unexpected outcome after twenty years of democracy – and yet the mobilisation of mine and farmworkers signals that many workers, including those whose power may seem very limited, are willing to take up the struggle against capital. The re-building of labour’s power in South Africa will pivot on the ability of progressive forces to (re)connect with workplace activism.

      Such outcomes are however all but unavoidable. In Brazil, after a brutal setback driven by neoliberal forces in the 1990s (with the Real Plan of 1994 mirroring GEAR), a labour-supported government has achieved an impressive reduction in poverty and inequality. This, according to Baltar et al. (2010), can be attributed to ‘minimum wage revaluation policy, social security, income transfers and improved wage bargaining’. The authors show that from 2004 onwards bargaining outcomes improved, entailing an increase in the wage share of value added. This is not surprising, and coherent with a ‘relational’ understanding of poverty (Oya op.cit.): when labour as a class reaps more benefits from growth than capital, inequality and poverty decrease. The Brazilian experience shows the need for state intervention to limit casualisation and increase minimum wages (and ensure they are applied), supported by trade unions strongly rooted in workplaces and able to bargain for better wages.

      The South African labour market presents a major analytical challenge. Why does employment intensity remain so low, in spite of very high unemployment (surplus labour) and evidence of a very flexible (or casual) labour market? In other words, why do employers not employ more people, especially in unskilled jobs, since cheap workers are widely available? It is unlikely that such questions can be answered with the limited tools of neoclassical economics; they will require a political economy approach which takes class (and class struggle) seriously. We hope that this chapter will help discard some of the myths surrounding the labour market, and encourage research which explores the heart of the matter, away from simplistic suggestions that ‘fixing education’ or making the labour market even more flexible than it is could be solutions to poverty.

      REFERENCES