David Elliott

Renewable Energy


Скачать книгу

gas-fired backup plants (usually the cheapest option) and energy storage facilities (usually more expensive) are not the only balancing technology options. As noted in the main text, demand can also be managed via smart grid/variable energy pricing to delay energy demand peaks when variable renewable inputs are low, and top-up power can be imported to meet the peaks via long-distance supergrids.

      Both those options can be low cost in operational terms. Indeed, flexible-demand management and smart grids can save money by reducing/shifting demand peaks, while supergrid links allow not just for balancing inputs but also for exports of surplus for some countries, earning a net positive income and avoiding the need for (wasteful) curtailment (or dumping) of surpluses. For example, a study by the UK government’s National Infrastructure Commission claimed that an integrated flexible supply-and-demand management system, with smart grids, storage and also grid interconnector imports/exports, could save the United Kingdom £8 billion per annum by 2030 (NIC 2017). A study by Imperial College/OVO Energy claimed that just adding residential flexibility in domestic energy use (including for electric vehicle charging) could reduce whole-system costs by up to £6.9 billion per annum or 21% of total electricity-system costs. It was suggested that these savings could more than offset the cost of upgrading the power system. That does seem credible for some of the options. For example, introducing variable time-of-use energy tariff charges requires no capital outlay but would lead to reduced peak energy use and user costs and also lower system costs (Ovo/Imperial 2018). In all, it has been suggested that, if fully developed, system flexibility and integration could save the United Kingdom up to £40 billion by 2050 (Bairstow 2019a).

      As noted above, as the renewable proportion goes up, so do the balancing costs, dramatically so in some modelling, for contributions of 70%, 80% and above. So savings like this would be welcome. However, there could be more savings to come if renewables expand even further. While balancing costs will rise until most power demand is met from renewables most of the time, after that any further expansion of renewable capacity, while requiring capital investment, will not incur extra power grid-balancing/backup costs. It will actually reduce the need for backup (more power would be available more often), while increasing the surplus that will be generated at times of low demand. The extra surplus would not be needed for balancing but would be available for heating, transport or export, or maybe conversion to hydrogen for these purposes, if that was the most lucrative option. In the latter case, more power-to-hydrogen conversion plants would be needed, but in either case the costs would be offset by the earnings from these end uses and the reduced system-balancing costs.

      Similar conclusions have emerged from studies by LUT University in Finland in conjunction with the Energy Watch Group (EWG) in Germany. They claim that 100% of energy, globally by 2050 or even earlier, is possible and would not cost more but in fact slightly less in direct cost terms: energy-generation costs would fall from €54/MWh for the system used in 2015 to €53/MWh with the new system, with balancing/storage, in 2050 (Ram et al. 2019). Note that neither the United States nor the European group saw nuclear as playing a role, not least because, as well as being expensive, it is inflexible and unable to balance variable renewables.

      Making cost predictions so far ahead is obviously hard, and there have been queries about the use of projected average global capital costs for the calculations (Egli, Steffen and Schmidt 2019), given that there may be important local variations. However, that is difficult to predict, whereas the LUT researchers believe global-trend projections may be more reliable (Bogdanov, Child and Breyer 2019).

      How rapidly can all this happen?

      New technology development, and more so system change, takes time, but the view that it is inevitably a slow process has been challenged (Lovins et al. 2018; Sovacool 2016). It has been argued that the transition to 100% renewable electricity could occur much more rapidly than suggested by historical energy transitions (Diesendorf and Elliston 2018), with concerns about climate change helping to speed the process.

      The recent pace of development and take-up of PV and batteries, as well as electric vehicles, certainly suggests that change can happen quickly. Although there has been no shortage of speculation over the likely impact of ‘destructive innovation’ of this sort on energy industry incumbents, there have been proposals for the very rapid expansion of renewables in response to what some have portrayed as a climate emergency, for example to around 80% of UK electricity by 2030 (Greenpeace 2019). The global Extinction Rebellion campaign even called for ‘zero carbon’ by 2025 in an attempt to shift the definition of what is politically possible, so as to make it more in line with what is deemed scientifically necessary for ecosystem survival (ER 2019).

      However, although the public mood may be changing, especially amongst the young, and renewable growth continues, it is wise to be a little cautious about what can be done in practice and how quickly it can be done: it may take time, and the political context sometimes does not support too much optimism. Support levels for renewables have been cut in many countries so, some say, the initial subsidy-based boom may falter.

      I will be looking at the overall cost of transitions like this in chapter 8 but, for Germany, the BDI put the overall net additional investment needed, set against the likely savings, at around €470 billion and €960 billion respectively (for the 80% and 95% emissions cuts) by 2050, or roughly €15 billion and €30 billion per year, around 0.4–0.8% of Germany’s gross domestic product (GDP).

      That is all a little speculative and some way off, whereas for the moment the reality is that, although funding programmes are continuing, investment-level growth in Germany and elsewhere is falling. Some critics argue that the recent fall in investment is due to the realization that renewables are expensive and that supporting rapid expansion with subsidies passes on unsustainable costs to consumers or taxpayers. That argument has been used in Germany, where guaranteed-price feed-in tariffs, which were very successful at building up renewable capacity, have been